Government debt

Taking debt can allow governments to conduct fiscal policy more effectively, avoid tax increases, and making investments with long-term returns.[8][9] Public debt has been linked to the rise of democracy, private financial markets, and modern economic growth.[7] Low-income, highly indebted states tend to attain loans from multilateral development banks and other governments because they are considered too risky for private investors.[2]: 208, s7.238 A country's general government debt-to-GDP ratio is an indicator of its debt burden since GDP measures the value of goods and services produced by an economy during a period (usually a year).For example, deficit financing can be used to maintain government services during a recession when tax revenues fall and expenses rise for say unemployment benefits.[8][9] For example, in the 17th and 18th centuries England established a parliament that included creditors, as part of a larger coalition, whose authorization had to be secured for the country to borrow or raise taxes.[8]: 10–16  But the founding of the Bank of England in 1694 revolutionised public finance and put an end to defaults such as the Great Stop of the Exchequer of 1672, when Charles II had suspended payments on his bills.In 1815, at the end of the Napoleonic Wars, British government debt reached a peak of more than 200% of GDP,[17] nearly 887 million pounds sterling.[18] The debt was paid off over 90 years by running primary budget surpluses (that is, revenues were greater than spending after payment of interest).[6] The COVID-19 pandemic caused public debt to soar in 2020, particularly in advanced economies that put in place sweeping fiscal measures.In an extreme case, in the 1920s Weimar Germany suffered from hyperinflation when the government used money creation to pay off the national debt following World War I.[2]: 76  An example of an explicit contingent liability is a public sector loan guarantee, where the government is required to make payments only if the debtor defaults.[2]: 210, s.7.252  Examples of implicit contingent liabilities include ensuring the payment of future social security pension benefits, covering the obligations of subnational governments in the event of a default, and spending for natural disaster relief.[44] In 2010 the European Commission required EU Member Countries to publish their debt information in standardized methodology, explicitly including debts that were previously hidden in a number of ways to satisfy minimum requirements on local (national) and European (Stability and Growth Pact) level.
Government debt-to-GDP ratio in % (2024, IMF)
The sealing of the Bank of England Charter (1694)
Centre: George III, drawn as a paunchy man with pockets bulging with gold coins, receives a wheel-barrow filled with the money-bags from William Pitt, whose pockets also overflow with coin. To the left, a quadriplegic veteran begs on the street. To the right, George, Prince of Wales, is depicted dressed in rags.
A new way to pay the National Debt , James Gillray , 1786. King George III , with William Pitt handing him another moneybag.
National Debt Clock outside the IRS office in NYC , April 20, 2012
Public financePoliciesAgriculturalEconomicEnergyIndustrialInvestmentSocialFiscalMonetaryPolicy mixFiscal policyBudgetpolicyinternalDeficit / surplusFinance ministryFiscal unionRevenueSpendingdeficitMonetary policyBank reservesrequirementsDiscount windowGold reservesInterest rateMonetary authoritycentral bankcurrency boardMonetary baseMonetary (currency) unionMoney supplyTrade policyBalance of tradeFree tradeGains from tradeNon-tariff barrierProtectionismTariffTrade blocTrade creationTrade diversionTrade / commerce ministryNon-tax revenueTax revenueDiscretionary spendingMandatory spendingBalanced budgetEconomic growthPrice stabilityFiscal adjustmentMonetary reformexternal debtgovernment deficitsgross domestic productGreat RecessionCOVID-19 recessionstate formationstate buildingdemocracyfinancial marketsmultilateral development banksWorld Banksovereign bondsRatings agenciesdebt-to-GDP ratioInternational Monetary FundWorld War IIbalanced budget rules"debt brake" in GermanyEuropean UnionStability and Growth PactBank of EnglandGreat Stop of the ExchequerCharles IIJames GillrayKing George IIINapoleonic WarsNational Debt Clockdebt crisisdeleveragingLatin American debt crisisArgentina's debt crisis in 2001Ricardian equivalencegovernment debt and household debtprint moneyinterest ratestaxationeconomic crisesinflationCredit riskConfederate States of AmericaAmerican Civil Warrefused to accept responsibility forImperial Russia'sfiat moneymoney creationeurozoneGreek government-debt crisisbailoutdebt monetizationWeimar Germany suffered from hyperinflationWorld War Ibalance sheetMedicareSocial Securitygovernment debtEuropean CommissionGovernment bondGovernment budget balanceMunicipal bondGovernment budget deficitGovernment spendingGenerational accountingFinancial repressionDebt clockSovereign defaultSovereign credit1980s austerity policy in RomaniaEuropean debt crisisNational debt of the United StatesBond (finance)Credit default swapWarrant (of Payment)List of countries by credit ratingList of countries by external debtList of countries by government debtWorld debtFinancial TimesStasavage, DavidChisholm, HughEncyclopædia BritannicaThe Washington PostBibcodeThe TimesEncyclopedia.comThe EconomistMarketWatchWikisourceNew International EncyclopediaWayback MachineEisner, RobertDavid R. HendersonConcise Encyclopedia of EconomicsLibrary of Economics and LibertyCorporateDebentureGovernmentMunicipalBusiness loanConsumer lendingLoan sharkPayday loanPredatory lendingVendor financeBankruptcyConsolidationManagement planReliefhistoryRestructuringDebt snowball methodDebtor-in-possession (DIP) financingLoan guaranteeCollectionEvasionBad debtCharge-offComplianceDebt bondageDebtors' prisonDistraintGarnishmentPhantom debtStrategic defaultTax refund interceptionMarketsConsumerDiplomacyMedicalVentureDeposit accountFixed incomeMoney marketSecuritizationConsumer leverage ratioExternalOdious debtDefaultInsolvencyInterestPromissory noteDerivatives marketDerivative (finance)OptionsDelta neutralExerciseExpirationMoneynessOpen interestPin riskRisk-free interest rateStrike priceSynthetic positionthe GreeksVolatilityVanillasAmericanBond optionEmployee stock optionEuropeanOption stylesWarrantsExoticsBarrierBasketBinaryCallable bull/bear contractChooserCliquetCommodoreCompoundForward startLookbackRainbowSpreadSwaptionStrategiesBackspreadBox spreadButterflyCalendar spreadCollarCondorCovered optionCredit spreadDebit spreadDiagonal spreadIntermarket spreadIron butterflyIron condorJelly rollLadderNaked optionStraddleStrangleProtective optionRatio spreadRisk reversalVertical spreadValuationBachelierBinomialBlack–ScholesequationFinite differenceHestonLatticesMargrabePut–call parityMC SimulationReal optionsTrinomialVanna–VolgaAmortisingCommodityConditional varianceConstant maturityCorrelationCredit defaultCurrencyDividendEquityForward Rate AgreementOvernight indexedTotal returnVarianceYear-on-year inflation-indexedZero CouponZero-coupon inflation-indexedForwardsFuturesContangoCurrency futureDividend futureForward marketForward priceForward rateInterest rate futureMarginNormal backwardationPerpetual futuresSingle-stock futuresSlippageStock market index futureExotic derivativesCommodity derivativeEnergy derivativeFreight derivativeInflation derivativeProperty derivativeWeather derivativeCollateralized debt obligation (CDO)Constant proportion portfolio insuranceContract for differenceCredit-linked note (CLN)Credit default optionCredit derivativeEquity-linked note (ELN)Equity derivativeForeign exchange derivativeFund derivativeFund of fundsInterest rate derivativeMortgage-backed securityPower reverse dual-currency note (PRDC)Consumer debtCorporate debtMunicipal debtTax policy